BROOKINGS
Immigration and the macroeconomy in the second Trump administration
Wendy Edelberg, Cecilia Esterline, Stan Veuger, and Tara Watson
December 3, 2024
Key takeaways:
The authors consider likely paths for net migration during the second Trump administration and their macroeconomic implications.
Overall, immigration policy under the new Trump administration could reduce 2025 GDP growth by between 0.1 (“high” scenario) and 0.4 percentage points (“low” scenario), or by $30 to $110 billion.
U.S. flag
Shutterstock / remotevfx.com
24 min read
Sections
What will net immigration flows look like after 2024?
Macroeconomic consequences
Conclusion
References
What will net immigration flows look like after 2024?
Macroeconomic consequences
Conclusion
References
Contact
Economic Studies Media Office
esmedia@brookings.edu
Follow the authors
@WendyEdelberg
@CecEsterline
@stanveuger
@taraelizwatson
More On
Immigrants & Immigration
U.S. Economy
U.S. Government & Politics
Program
Economic Studies
Editor's note: This is an update to an October 2024 analysis, which is archived here.
Few issues dominated the 2024 presidential contest like immigration. In this analysis, we consider likely paths for net migration during president-elect Trump’s second term and their macroeconomic implications.
The starting point for our analysis is the creation of a “high immigration” and a “low immigration” scenario. These scenarios reflect a combination of the historical record under the first Trump administration, the incoming administration’s announced immigration policies, as well as our judgment of likely developments. They are constructed from the ground up, starting by predicting inflows from specific visa categories, border and parole policy, and entries without inspection. We also predict removals, reflecting both the Trump campaign’s positioning and logistical constraints as well as other factors that affect outflows.
We provide two scenarios given the considerable uncertainty about policy actions as well as responses by migrants. We think of the scenarios as spanning the range of plausible policy actions, something like the 20th percentile of resulting net flows (“low”) to the 80th percentile (“high”).
In the first two years of the “low” scenario, in which we anticipate the most acute departure from recent policy, we expect the United States to see net outmigration—that is, the extraordinary case of more people leaving the country than entering. Under this scenario, in 2025 migration would be -650,000.
The “high” scenario assumes immigration policy is only modestly more aggressive than it was in the first Trump administration. Resulting immigration flows would be positive 1.3 million in 2025. To be sure, immigration flows could be outside the range of our scenarios. During the campaign, Trump called for immediate mass deportations more than 10 times what we incorporate even in our “low” scenario.
We show how the different scenarios would involve different patterns of population growth over the coming years. The cumulative growth in the total civilian non-institutionalized population over age 16 (CNIP) over four years, including both U.S.-born and foreign-born people, ranges from as little as 4 million people to 8 million people depending on the scenario. The latter number is similar to what would result from the continuation of average CNIP growth between January 2000 and January 2024.
We use CNIP population growth to predict labor force growth, considering the mix of skills and earnings power immigrants are likely to bring. A reduction in labor force growth from lower immigration brings with it reduced growth in earnings, consumption, and output. When greater immigration adds more to the labor force, the opposite happens.
Ultimately, we project that immigration policy under the new Trump administration will reduce 2025 GDP growth by between 0.1 (“high” scenario) and 0.4 percentage points (“low” scenario), or by $30 to $110 billion. Beyond 2025, the economy under the “low” scenario would continue to be notably smaller than the economy under the other scenarios. The consequences of a more extreme mass deportation policy would be economically disruptive in unpredictable ways and are not modeled here.
In Partnership With
AEI Logo and Logotype
Niskanen Center logo
What will net immigration flows look like after 2024?
Figure 1: Cumulative net migration under two immigration scenarios since 2011
Net immigration is determined by a combination of inflows and outflows. Estimates of these flows are subject to significant uncertainty even in retrospect (see e.g., Edelberg and Watson 2024). Here we analyze the macroeconomic implications of net immigration rates during the next presidential term (2025–28) and immediately afterward, which are subject to multiple additional layers of uncertainty. Net migration flows from our two scenarios are shown in figure 1 and reflect that uncertainty.1
Of course, immigration flows are not only determined by U.S. immigration policy. They are also subject to shocks from push and pull factors, like humanitarian crises abroad or fluctuations in economic performance at home. The strong U.S. labor market in the past two years was likely a driver of the relatively high rates of net immigration, and it is unlikely we would have seen as many recent Ukrainian and Venezuelan arrivals without the collapse of the Venezuelan economy or Russia’s full-scale invasion of Ukraine. Non-immigration policy can also affect these push and pull factors in ways we have not modeled here. In addition, our scenarios implicitly assume that the menu of feasible immigration policy options is constrained by the moderating influence of the courts, public opinion, Congress, and state and local authorities.
For each scenario we estimate the number of individuals obtaining permanent residency from abroad and entering on regular nonimmigrant visas (excluding business visitors, tourists, and travelers in transit) or through a refugee resettlement program. We assume that the Trump administration will affect these legal migration inflows for four years, after which point they revert to long-run levels which are assumed to be the same in both scenarios starting in 2029. We also model inflows for the humanitarian parole programs for Cubans, Haitians, Nicaraguans, and Venezuelans (CHNV) and Ukrainians (U4U), individuals who enter the country without inspection, and encounters at or between ports of entry that lead to a migrant receiving a notice to appear (NTA) or other forms of parole.
From this total inflow we subtract outmigration flows. We assume typical exit rates among different categories of migrants such as those who entered in the prior two years with a permanent immigrant visa (4 percent), those who entered in the past two years on a regular nonimmigrant visa (20 percent), those who entered without inspection over the past two years (4 percent), and the stock of the long-term foreign-born population (2 percent). In 2025, we model the total foreign-born stock by starting with the Census 2023 estimate of 47.8 million, netting out mortality, and adding our 2.7 million estimate for 2024 net migration. To allocate the total stock across arrival categories, we use legal visas issued and port-of-entry border flows for FY 2023 as a proxy for 2023 and extrapolated data for FY 2024 to proxy for 2024. For border encounters between ports of entry, we used calendar year data for 2023 and extrapolated calendar year data for 2024. We also use the Congressional Budget Office’s (CBO) estimate of 860,000 entries without inspection in 2023 and assume it applies to 2024. The differences in exits from these categories between the two scenarios emerge only from the different stocks of immigrants which result from differential inflows.
We also model some outflows that are directly affected by policy decisions. These include removals due to interior enforcement, voluntary responses to that enforcement, and removals that result from adjudication of recent parole or notice to appear (NTA) cases. Interior enforcement estimates are based on historical patterns as described below, except that the first two years of the “low” scenario generate five times the interior removals as the historical average observed in Trump’s first term. Interior enforcement differences are especially pronounced in the first two years and gradually return to an assumed long-run level, which is the same across all scenarios by 2029. In the “high” scenario we assume that voluntary exits due to enforcement equal 15 percent of the interior removals, to reflect chilling effects and out-migration of other family members when one family member is deported. In the “low” scenario we assume the chilling effects will be much more significant. These assumptions are inherently speculative. Finally, we allow for a range of possibilities for exit rates among individuals who have arrived recently as asylum-seekers and parolees, many of whom will lose the legal right to stay in the United States during the next four years.
Figure 2 summarizes the inflows and outflows by category for 2025 for both scenarios and the resulting net migration for that year. Though immigration inflows gradually converge and are assumed to reach the same levels by 2029 under both scenarios, there are significantly different stocks of migrants in the U.S. in that year under the different scenarios. A greater number of immigrants in the U.S. in 2029 means greater numbers of emigration in later years; as a result, the “high” scenario has greater outflows and lower net migration rates after 2029 (figure 1).
Figure 2: Net migration flows in 2025 under two immigration scenarios
The remainder of this section discusses the assumptions underlying our scenarios in more detail.
High
The high-immigration scenario under a second Trump administration is one in which legal immigration policy reflects the pre-pandemic Trump administration with the consequences of enforcement reflecting the record of the Trump administration while recognizing the higher levels of border activity seen in the past few years.
In this scenario, for each visa category and the refugee resettlement program we take the average number of arrivals from 2017 through 2019. We assume these levels stay in place throughout the four years. We assume the CHNV and U4U programs are terminated and take the average number of encounters from 2017 through 2019 that led to NTA or parole; these levels are in place for two years and then gradually return to the assumed long run.
This scenario assumes lower levels of border enforcement for the first two years and includes 900,000 entries without inspection. These categories gradually return to an assumed long-run level by 2029. We assume interior removals equal to their 2017–2019 average for the first two years, then a gradual return to the assumed long-run level. We assume voluntary removals in response to enforcement equal to 15 percent the number of interior removals. In addition, we assume 15 percent of those who arrived with NTA/parole in the prior two years are removed. Finally, we assume the same exit rates for other recent arrivals and long-term residents described above for all scenarios.
The “high” scenario has net migration of around 1.3 million in 2025. Cumulative net migration is around 5.8 million over four years.
Low
The Trump low-immigration scenario is one in which legal immigration is slightly below where it was during the pre-pandemic Trump administration, while enforcement and deportation efforts reach levels not seen in recent decades. Trump has sometimes alluded to an Eisenhower-era mass deportation effort, offensively named “Operation Wetback,” which may have been responsible for removing over a million people from the country in 1954. The “low” scenario we model involves fewer annual removals than that episode and many fewer than some of stated aims on the campaign trail, but nevertheless would represent a dramatic shift from the current enforcement environment. This is the scenario with the lowest cumulative net migration rate of the four scenarios we analyze.
In this scenario, for each visa category we take the average number of arrivals from 2017 through 2019 and reduce it by 5 percent. We further reduce student visas by 90,000 according to Project 2025 proposals (Esterline 2024) and reduce refugee resettlement to 15,000 per year. We assume these inflows would hold for the four years of an administration, after which time policy would revert to the long-run level in 2029.
For 2025 and 2026, we assume the CHNV and U4U programs are terminated. We assess that only 200,000 people will enter without inspection as border enforcement is significantly ramped up. We take the average number of border encounters at or between ports of entry from 2017 through 2019 that led to NTA or parole and reduce it by 25 percent, under the assumption of a less hospitable border environment than the first Trump term. For all of these categories, we assume that after the first two years inflows will gradually return to an assumed long-run level by 2029.
Due to logistical, financial, legal, and political constraints, the “low” scenario assumes enforcement would be less pronounced than the full scope of mass deportation of all undocumented immigrants which Trump has sometimes articulated. Nevertheless, this scenario would still reflect an extreme level of immigration enforcement relative to living memory. We assume interior removals will equal five times their 2017–2019 average for 2025 and 2026, gradually returning to their long-term level by 2029. And we assume voluntary outmigration in response to enforcement will rise to 50 percent the number of interior removals each year due to chilling effects from extreme enforcement environment. In addition, we assume 25 percent of those who arrived with NTA/parole in the prior two years are removed, as would happen if the parole programs were terminated and asylum applications were denied at an elevated rate. All other assumptions are unchanged.
Unlike the “high” scenario, the “low” scenario yields net negative migration. Net migration is around -650,000 in 2025 and -120,000 in 2026, after which time it becomes positive. Cumulative net migration over the four years is around 630,000.
Macroeconomic consequences
With declining fertility and an aging population, net immigration has constituted the vast majority of population growth since the pandemic (CBO 2024c). Beginning in 2025, net immigration is different for each scenario we consider, which leads to different growth rates for the population. In order to estimate what those immigration paths imply for the macroeconomy, we estimate how many of the arriving immigrants would be part of the civilian non-institutionalized population over the age of 16, because that comprises the people who could potentially add to the U.S. labor force. We estimate the fraction of immigrants that would be part of that population using the American Community Survey (2015–2022) and the Current Population Survey (2023–2024). Figure 3 shows our estimates of what the high- and low-migration scenarios would imply for the cumulative increase in the civilian non-institutionalized population over the age of 16 from 2025 through 2028. Panel A shows cumulative net migration in this population, and Panel B models the total cumulative population growth, including the natural increase. In the “low” scenario, the cumulative increase in the civilian non-institutionalized population over age 16 is 4 million people through 2028 versus 8 million in the “high” scenario.
Figure 3: Cumulative civilian non-institutionalized population increase from January 2025 under two immigration scenarios
Similarly, we use survey evidence from recent years to estimate what fraction of the adult immigrant population would participate in the labor force conditional on how long those immigrants have been in the U.S., what fraction has a college degree, the unemployment rates for recent immigrants with and without a college degree, and average earnings for those groups. This produces, for both scenarios, a path for the number of additional workers, by skill level and associated level of earnings, in the labor force for each future year. Those earnings underlie the estimated output generated by U.S. immigrants that are reflected in the first rows of tables 1 and 2 below.
Table 1: Effect on real GDP growth in 2025 from change in immigration flows under two immigration scenarios, in percentage points
Different rates of labor force growth and different paths of labor market earnings will translate into different levels of output. Table 1 shows the effect on real GDP growth in 2025 by its components, and figure 4 visualizes the total effect of each scenario on GDP growth.
The first row of table 1 shows what the resulting direct effect on real GDP growth in 2025 would be from the different labor market outcomes in the two scenarios. The immigration path under the “high” scenario, with net immigration of 1.2 million next year, would reduce GDP growth by 0.1 percentage point in 2025 compared to the boost from immigration in 2024, while the “low” scenario would reduce GDP growth by 0.4 percentage points.
The second row of table 1 shows the additional effect on economic growth stemming from the unexpected reduction in consumer spending, which would be affected by the change in net immigration in 2025. Generally, these aggregate economic effects are estimated to be small. Unexpected changes in consumer spending are predicted to affect the economy because of the responses of businesses facing lower demand. In essence, if businesses have made hiring and production decisions for 2025 assuming that the growth in near-term demand will be similar to that in 2024, they will be surprised when spending growth turns out to be different, and will respond accordingly. If net immigration flows were zero in 2025 and consumer spending grows more slowly as a result, some businesses would lay workers off or otherwise pull back on production. (Those laid-off workers might be U.S.-born or immigrants remaining in the U.S.)
To estimate the initial effect on consumer spending, we assume that the rate of saving among the immigrants who would have otherwise been in the U.S. in 2025 would equal 5.1 percent, the nationwide average rate in year-to-date 2024. On one hand, the saving rate among recent immigrants could be higher than that of the general population to the degree that they send that income abroad in the form of remittances rather than spending it on U.S. goods and services. On the other hand, their saving rate could be lower than the general population to the degree that recent immigrants have significant spending needs and few financial resources to draw on. In the end, we use the national saving rate and note the estimated effects on consumer spending are not particularly sensitive to moderate differences in the saving rate assumption.
The third row of table 1 shows an effect we think is only notable in the “low” scenario: an increase in precautionary saving by immigrants faced with an extreme enforcement environment. In this scenario, we assess that saving rates would rise among recent immigrants who remain in the U.S. More precisely, we estimate that their rate of saving would be 8 percent, just above the national average of the saving rate in 2019, instead of 5.1 percent. This effect further reduces real GDP growth in 2025 by a small amount. Of course, if the saving rate rose more, or if more people than we estimate increased saving rates, the effect on spending and output would be more negative.
In our analysis, monetary policy in 2025 is largely unresponsive to the economic effects of changes in immigration in either scenario. Normally, one would expect the Federal Reserve to make monetary policy more accommodative in the face of an unexpected reduction in aggregate demand, in part because that reduction in aggregate demand spurs an unwelcome reduction in inflation. However, in the scenarios we examine, both actual output and the economy’s ability to produce goods and services would be dampened. We therefore use the average of fiscal multipliers that are relevant when monetary policy is mostly unresponsive to changes in demand (Whalen and Reichling 2015).
A lower level of immigration reduces the economy’s ability to produce goods and services because it reduces the size of the labor force. In the near term, a reduction in the size of the labor force—all else equal—makes it more expensive for firms to produce goods and services and thus results in higher inflation. For example, McKibbin, Hogan, and Noland (2024) estimate that a reduction in labor supply of 1.3 million workers resulting from mass deportations would raise the price level by 1.5 percent over three years (or, in other words, raise the rate of inflation by an average of 0.5 percentage point from 2025 to 2028).
In our assessment, the effect on inflation in the near term would be smaller than that estimate for two reasons. First, we estimate that the reduction in the supply of labor would be smaller than 1.3 million in 2025, even under our “low” scenario. Second, we estimate that the reduction in aggregate demand, as described above, would be roughly as significant as the reduction in the economy’s ability to produce goods and services. Broadly, we expect that prices would rise for some goods and services where supply would be reduced and demand is inelastic (such as agricultural goods and home health aide services), and prices would fall for others where demand would be reduced and supply is inelastic (such as rental housing in areas with large concentrations of immigrants). Slowing immigration may increase aggregate inflation in the near term, but, in our assessment, the net effect would be modest.
Several potentially important effects are not included in the estimates summarized in table 1. For example, these estimates do not include any change in corporate profits or other kinds of capital income that might immediately result from the change in labor supply in 2025. In addition, these estimates do not include any broad change in business or consumer sentiment that might lead to additional changes in investment or household spending.
Figure 4: Effect on GDP growth in 2025 under two immigration scenarios, in percentage points
Under both scenarios, cumulative net migration would be positive by 2034. As a result, the size of the labor force would be larger than in a comparison benchmark where net migration is zero in every year between 2025 and 2034. Table 2 shows the estimated effect on the level of GDP in 2034 relative to a benchmark under which there is no additional net migration.
Table 2: Effect on level of real GDP in 2034 under two immigration scenarios relative to scenario with no additional net migration, percent
The second row of table 2 shows the estimated effect on output from greater capital investment. Because immigrants coming to the U.S. between 2025 and 2034 would require equipment and infrastructure to effectively do their jobs, we expect that the capital stock would be proportionally larger in scenarios with more immigration. Investors would receive greater capital income as a result. The third row combines the effects of greater labor supply and a larger capital stock.
These estimates do not incorporate any positive effects on productivity directly owing to immigration. In particular, the CBO estimates that “innovations generated by immigrants working in STEM occupations increase productivity” (CBO 2024a). Based on CBO’s estimate, incorporating such an effect might increase the level of GDP in 2034 under the “high” scenario by roughly 0.2 percent relative to GDP under the “low” scenario.
The analysis highlights two important points. In the near term, a sharp reduction in net migration would dampen real GDP growth. This is because such a reduction would mean a smaller labor force and thus a smaller number of people producing goods and services. Specifically, if net migration fell from significantly positive in 2024 to -650,000 in 2025, as under the “low” scenario, the reduction in production of output by immigrants would subtract 0.2 percentage points off GDP growth next year (as shown in the first row of table 1). Consistent with smaller growth in the labor force, we expect that monthly employment growth would be considerably lower in 2025 than in 2024. Specifically, we estimate that the reversal from positive net migration to negative net migration would reduce employment growth by almost 100,000 a month.
In addition, the reduction in consumer spending resulting from negative migration in the “low” scenario would lead businesses to cut back on investment and hiring, which would further reduce GDP growth by 0.1 percentage point. Finally, an effort to implement an aggressive deportation policy, even falling short of the mass deportation implied by rhetoric, would likely reduce spending among immigrants who remain in the U.S., which we estimate would further reduce GDP growth. If net migration in 2025 were even more negative than under the “low” scenario, the economic effects would be more negative.
The immigration scenarios also have differing implications for the U.S. economy over the longer-term. Relative to a path with no net immigration between 2025 and 2034, the “low” and “high” scenarios raise the level of real GDP in 2034 by between 1.5 percent and 2.1 percent, respectively. The difference between the two scenarios would naturally be larger if we assumed that immigration policy is “sticky” instead of returning to a common long-run baseline after the 2025-2029 presidential term.
Our assumptions for the “low” scenario imply 3.0 million total removals over four years, falling well short of the deportation aspirations of Trump’s campaign rhetoric. A higher deportation rate would have more adverse macroeconomic consequences, and would disrupt labor markets, supply chains, and civil society in unpredictable ways beyond what we have modeled here. While we deem full implementation of the campaign rhetoric unrealistic, analysis conducted by McKibbin et al. (2024) finds that the aggregate economic impacts of removing 7.5 million workers in 2025 would be even more profound than what our estimates show, both in the short term and in the long term.
Conclusion
Given the long-term trends of fertility rates and population aging in the U.S., immigration is projected to be an increasingly important factor underlying labor force growth (Vespa, Medina, and Armstrong 2018). Policies that constrain immigration would shrink the size of the labor force. In addition, immigration has been shown to raise productivity, generating further long-run growth that has not been incorporated into our estimates.
The consequences for the aggregate economy are clear, but the fiscal effects of immigration are also worth noting. Immigration improves the federal budget because immigrants pay more in federal income and payroll taxes than they use in federal benefits. In a 2017 consensus report, the National Academy of Sciences calculated that the marginal benefit to the federal budget of each additional new immigrant and their descendants over 75 years is $326,000 in present value (2023 dollars, or $259,000 in the study as reported in 2012 dollars). However, states and localities often face fiscal challenges in the short run when absorbing new arrivals; see Edelberg and Watson (2022) for a proposal to address that imbalance.
Regardless of how immigration flows play out over the next four years, there is widespread agreement that the immigration system is in need of repair. The lack of congressional direction in this area contributes to the large amounts of discretion wielded by the executive branch. The time is long overdue for Congress to grapple with immigration reform.
References
Authors
Wendy Edelberg headshot
Wendy Edelberg
Director - The Hamilton Project, Senior Fellow - Economic Studies
@WendyEdelberg
Cecilia Esterline headshot
Cecilia Esterline
Senior Immigration Policy Analyst - Niskanen Center
@CecEsterline
Headshot
Stan Veuger
Senior Fellow - American Enterprise Institute, Visiting Lecturer - Harvard University
@stanveuger
Tara Watson headshot
Tara Watson
Director - Center for Economic Security and Opportunity, John C. and Nancy D. Whitehead Chair, Senior Fellow - Economic Studies
No comments:
Post a Comment